i58 Egypt from military service, by which the far too lightly taxed wealthy families were made to pay from £40 to £100 to free their young men. By calling up two hundred and sixty-two thousand conscripts to replenish an army of eighteen thousand, ^250,000 was raised from the wealthier recruits in 1886. A more questionable, though more conventional, resource was the new tobacco duties. For to obtain this new and '' unaffected '' revenue a pro- mising native industry was sacrificed by a prohibition of tobacco cultivation. It was even more unfortunate that nothing effective could be done to redistribute the incidence of taxation, which still fell almost entirely on the land-worker, leaving his landlord very lightly burdened, and the foreigner almost entirely exempt. Agreement was, however, obtained (1885) for subject- ing foreigners to certain taxes. Nor can Cromerism claim to have reduced the debt. The reduction it effected corresponded pretty closely to the £9,000,000 that had been added, mostly to pay off the expenses of British intervention. Thus, at the end of Cromerism the capital value of the debt was much the same as at the beginning. What Cromerism can claim is that it saved Egypt from bankruptcy and from the consequent increase of foreign control, and gave it time to become so economically convalescent that it could bear the burden of the debt without breaking the back of the fellah. It is, of course, open to Egyptian Nationalists to claim that if we had let the national movement alone it could have got from Europe an equitable reduction of an usurious debt and a revision of the Capitulations and Conventions that aggravated the burden of its charges (Dass Mahomed, Land of the Pharaohs, p. 290). Also they may contend that the reforms of Cromerism could have been equally well carried out by Egyptian Con-